Why Jobs Don’t Justify Government Spending

Government jobs aren’t a free lunch.
Why Jobs Don’t Justify Government Spending
U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Public Domain
Peter Jacobsen
Updated:
0:00
Commentary
My colleague, Maggie Anders, recently made an insightful post on X: “‘But people will lose their jobs’ is not a legitimate argument for continuing to pump taxpayer dollars into the bloated federal government. Sorry.”

As President Donald Trump begins to shutter government bureaus (or at least pieces of them), many are highlighting an obvious downside: Government employees will lose jobs if you shut down government agencies.

Some articles are calling it the biggest layoff in history, and saying it will have serious, negative economic consequences. Others hedge by saying the impact may not be felt for a long time.

Of course, it is unfortunate when people lose their jobs in and of itself. However, it does not follow that every job is worth preserving.

When any job is created, government or otherwise, it comes with a potential upside and downside. The upside is the value the job produces both for the individual and for the rest of society based on what they produce in their job. The downside is that the individual’s time and the resources they use to accomplish their job cannot be allocated to the production of alternative goods. Economists call these foregone opportunities the opportunity cost of the job.

In private markets, companies compare the upside of a person’s job with the downside by looking at how much the worker produces (in terms of additional revenue generated) and comparing that to how much they cost to employ (in terms of wages, benefits, and so on). If a new job produces more revenue than it costs in terms of resources, the job will be created because it adds to the company’s profitability. If a new job costs more than the revenue it brings in, then this implies that other uses of those resources are expected to be more urgently demanded by consumers. In this case, the company would make a loss, and the new job would not be created.

On the flip side, when the government creates jobs, no such accounting takes place. Since politicians and bureaucrats do not operate through profit and loss, there is no way to see if the value of the resources used is greater than the value of the services provided. To quote the economist Ludwig von Mises:

“A government is not a profit-seeking enterprise. The conduct of its affairs cannot be checked by profit-and-loss statements. Its achievement cannot be valued in terms of money.”

The upside of government programs is easily visible—when the government builds a new bridge, you can see people use the bridge. However, the downside is less clear. The money and resources the government took from taxpayers to build the bridge and hire employees could have been used for other things, but since politicians take these resources from voters via taxation, they do not bear the cost and cannot account for it.

In “Economics in One Lesson,” Henry Hazlitt makes a related point about governments building bridges:

“When providing employment becomes the end [of building the bridge], need becomes a subordinate consideration. ‘Projects’ have to be invented. Instead of thinking only where bridges must be built, the government spenders begin to ask themselves where bridges can be built.”

But don’t these jobs make society richer? Not so fast. Hazlitt continues:

“It is true that a particular group of bridgeworkers may receive more employment than otherwise. But the bridge has to be paid for out of taxes. For every dollar that is spent on the bridge a dollar will be taken away from taxpayers.”

The government can create jobs by taking tax dollars. However, some jobs are destructive to the wealth of society. It would be wasteful if some private company used millions of dollars of resources to dig holes in the ground and immediately refill them. The reason we don’t worry about this happening is that a company whose owners chose to do this would make massive losses.

No taxpayer would be happy with the government paying someone a six-figure salary to dig holes and fill them back in. But how can the government be sure that existing government jobs aren’t wealth-destroying? How can we tell if some positions are essentially just hole-digging-and-refilling positions? Without profit-and-loss accounting, we can’t.

The federal government is not fundamentally a jobs program—at least not if we want it to make the lives of citizens better. As such, the claim that cutting government is bad for the economy because people lose jobs does not follow. Those people will go on to find jobs in the private sector, where their new employers are subject to the desires of customers and the forces of competition, profit, and loss.

Maggie’s point here is absolutely correct. The government is not a jobs program.

Views expressed in this article are opinions of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of The Epoch Times.
Peter Jacobsen
Peter Jacobsen
Author
Peter Jacobsen is a writing fellow at the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE). He teaches economics and holds the positions of assistant professor of economics at Ottawa University and Gwartney Professor of Economic Education and Research at the Gwartney Institute. He received his graduate education at George Mason University.