What can possibly explain such a startling and enormous difference between a supposed poverty rate of 2 percent and an official poverty rate of 12.3? The answer is twofold, both having to do with how we measure wealth and poverty.
In the first place, this is an apples and oranges comparison. The official poverty rate strangely and confusingly includes some government assistance, but excludes the lion’s share, leaving about $1 trillion of assistance uncounted. The Gramm/Early computation includes all the gov’t benefits. Thus, Americans who are categorized as poor in terms of income have an actual standard of living that is not poor when one counts the government assistance they receive.
The second reason for the gaping disparity between the official poverty rate and the Gramm/Early poverty rate is due to major differences in how key macroeconomic data are measured. GDP, consumer price, and real wage indexes, inflation, productivity, and poverty rates all are inherently difficult to measure accurately. According to Gramm and Early, methodological flaws have resulted in all of these economic indicators making us appear less prosperous than we really are.
One seemingly insuperable obstacle in macroeconomic statistics is how to quantify improvements in quality. If you can figure that one out, you’re a lot smarter than I am. To me, this is comparable to the 19th-century Swiss economist Vilfredo Pareto’s attempt to quantify happiness—an unsolvable problem.
But there are other more down-to-earth calculations that can be improved upon. For example, Gramm and Early reject the oft-repeated assertion that real average hourly earnings increased only 6 percent from 1975 to 2017. They claim the actual figure is a 52 percent increase. Whether that figure hit the bullseye, I can’t say, but the 6 percent figure has long seemed unrealistic based on everyday observations of material standards of living.
The implications of using seriously flawed macroeconomic data to formulate public policy are profound and far-reaching. If, in fact, inflation has been overestimated while real wages, productivity, and GDP growth have been underestimated—and this is what Gramm and Early maintain—then government spending and debt have been rising much faster than they should. Many standing assumptions may in fact be erroneous.
Whether Gramm and Early have found the “right” way to compute macroeconomic data is a topic worthy of vigorous debate. Their upcoming book, “Freedom and Equality,” co-written with economist Robert Ekelund, will examine macro measurements in depth. This book could be one of the most impactful books on public policy in many years. My opinion is that we will never find exact, indisputably accurate ways to measure wealth and poverty, but we shouldn’t stop striving for accuracy. The present established methods are misrepresenting real-life economic conditions and need to be recalibrated.
Returning to the poverty issue, if is true that only 2 percent of Americans actually live in poverty, is it time to declare victory in the War on Poverty? I would respond with an emphatic no. While glad that few Americans live in serious want, as long as the only thing holding people above actual poverty is government spending, there’s further progress to be made. My reasons are several:
Economically, our entire society will be more prosperous if the millions who consume, say, $35,000 per year of goods and services were to actually contribute that much wealth production through their own labor. This is particularly true of the armies of bureaucrats who administer these programs. I mean no disrespect to the many caring, competent civil servants administering the myriad government anti-poverty programs, but they are not truly creating wealth; rather, they are simply redistributing it. And the most glaring economic reason: We can’t keep adding trillions of dollars to government debt indefinitely.
Ethically, we need to move away from the facile and dangerous notion that government should be in charge of redistributing property. The federal government was constituted to protect property rights, not abrogate them.
Politically, the trillion dollars per year now spent on poverty programs means that millions of Americans have gotten habituated to massive transfers of wealth. According to public choice theory, which states that government employees still respond to incentives just as much as anyone else, the anti-poverty bureaucrats don’t want to eliminate poverty. If they did, the reason for their jobs would evaporate. So instead, they seek to manage it. Indeed, with the relative fixity of the poverty rate over the past 50-plus years, they seem to have managed the problem quite successfully, repeatedly redefining poverty and keeping the numbers of poor from falling.
A final political objective is to lift people out of poverty, strengthening their dignity and self-esteem as they learn the satisfaction of becoming independent and self-supporting rather than dependent clients of the state. This will be a daunting and difficult challenge, but if Gramm, Early, and Ekelund are even half right about how flawed measurements have led to inferior policies, then it would behoove us to start making the necessary adjustments both to macroeconomic calculations and to public policies. Until then, Americans will remain poorer than we should be.