The Origin and Meaning of Profits

The Origin and Meaning of Profits
A cashier handles money in Macy's Herald Square in Manhattan, New York. Entrepreneurs can only make money if they help consumers solve a problem. Reuters/Andrew Kelly
Updated:

The definition of profit is the excess of revenue over costs. The underlying activity that produces the revenue, and incurs the cost, can be almost anything.

As Robert Nozick pointed out in his 1974 article “Why Intellectuals Oppose Capitalism,” intellectuals find this lack of definition in the goals and reward structure of capitalism frustrating. After all, intellectuals have spent their lives going to the best schools, getting the best grades, and congratulating each other on being the most important members of society.

By comparison, entrepreneurs and business people often are uneducated, sometimes even coarse. Socially, we tend to think of Al Czervik from the movie “Caddyshack”: If you make or do something, and a bunch of people happen to like it, enough so that you can charge more than it costs to make that thing, what kind of achievement is that?

For example, do you remember the “Pet Rock” of the mid-1970s? If not, ask your (grand)parents. In 1974, a guy named Gary Dahl was in a bar, listening to some friends complain about how much work it was to keep pets. He decided that a pet rock would be a lot less work. He bought nearly a ton of ordinary gray stones at a building supply warehouse. He marketed them in cardboard boxes that had air holes cut so the rock could “breathe.”

The real genius was including a 32-page “owner’s manual,” with instructions on training the pet: “sit” and “stay” were basic commands, graduating to “roll over,” and ultimately “attack” if the rock were thrown. The fad lasted about six months, with a burst of sales around Christmas in 1975. More than 1.5 million Pet Rocks were sold, and Dahl was moderately wealthy.

It appears that in 2012, an updated version of the Pet Rock was offered, with a USB cable for “added functionality.” It is no longer available, as far as I can tell, but I am pretty sure that the USB port and cable didn’t actually add any functionality at all. Nonetheless, quite a few people bought them.

Did Dahl produce any value for society? Does a pet rock that earns profits mean that someone should get rich? An intellectual would say, “I got straight A’s, and you didn’t even finish college, you filthy entrepreneur. We need redistribution based on social merit! Some idiot who sells rocks doesn’t deserve to be wealthy!”

The Origins of Profit

This kind of question simply reverses the cause-and-effect relationship between merit and earnings. The problem with the standard view of earnings is that wealth is, or should be, a reward for merit. But “social” merit is very hard to define; as Thomas Hobbes noted, in “Leviathan”: “A man may be Worthy of Riches, Office, and Employment, that nevertheless, can plead no right to have it before another; and therefore cannot be said to merit or deserve it.”

Right. But profit isn’t wealth awarded to people who have intrinsic social merit. Profit is the end consequence of a discovery process, a search for value that is distributed among all the many nooks and crannies of a modern economy.

Somerset Maugham wrote a famous short story titled “The Verger,” in which the main character, Mr. Foreman, has been working hard as a verger—a lay assistant to the vicar in the Anglican Church—for more than 15 years, since he was a teenager. A new vicar is appointed and is shocked to learn that the verger cannot read or write. The vicar demands that Mr. Foreman become literate, or leave the church’s employ.

Mr. Foreman doubts he can learn to read and is sacked. He wanders, looking for a cigarette. But there is no tobacconist anywhere on all the long street of shops.

Mr. Foreman has an idea, hardly a profound idea but an idea nonetheless, that he might open a shop. He makes substantial profits. Before long, he opens another, and then several more, in every case using the simple—in fact, obvious—strategy of finding an area of the city with many shops but no tobacconist.

He amasses a fortune. Worrying about having to mind all that cash, Mr. Foreman visits a bank, where he is told by an executive that he should invest the money. Mr. Foreman declines to invest in complex financial instruments, confiding in the banker that he can’t read or write. The banker is thunderstruck, finding it remarkable that an illiterate man could acquire substantial wealth.

The banker wonders out loud, given what a success Mr. Foreman has become without literacy, how things might be if he could read. “I can tell you that, sir,“ says Mr. Foreman, with a little smile. ”I’d be verger of St. Peter’s, Neville Square.”

Did Mr. Foreman deserve to become wealthy? He didn’t have any merit, at least as intellectuals measure such things. All he did was to make it possible for people buy a product they wanted, at a lower price (counting travel) than had been possible before. What’s so hard, or so admirable, about that?

Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises himself was honest about this feature of the profit and loss system: “The entrepreneurs are neither perfect nor good in any metaphysical sense. They owe their position exclusively to the fact that they are better fit for the performance of the functions incumbent upon them than other people are. They earn profit not because they are clever in performing their tasks, but because they are more clever or less clumsy than other people are.

“If the grumbler knew better, why did he not himself fill the gap and seize the opportunity to earn profits? It is easy indeed to display foresight after the event. In retrospect, all fools become wise.”

Entrepreneurial Awareness

In 1978, Israel Kirzner, a student of Mises, gave a classic description of the relation between profit, value, and entrepreneurship: correcting errors.

“We understand, that is, that the initial imperfection in knowledge is to be attributed, not to lack of some needed resource, but to fail to notice opportunities ready at hand. The multiplicity of prices represented opportunities for pure entrepreneurial profit; that such multiplicity existed, means that many market participants (those who sold at the lower prices and those who bought at the higher prices) simply overlooked these opportunities.

“Since these opportunities were left unexploited, not because of unavailable needed resources, but because they were simply not noticed, we understand that, as time passes, the lure of available pure profits can be counted upon to alert at least some market participants to the existence of these opportunities.”

Kirzner defined entrepreneurship as “awareness,” the constant searching for profit opportunities. But Kirzner conceived of errors much more broadly than the above passage would suggest. Rather than simply “correcting” errors in the price system, and causing the convergence of prices of a single existing commodity, entrepreneurs imagine alternative futures, new products, and possible ways of organizing production.

It is difficult to overstate the importance of this distinction. An entrepreneur doesn’t (just) take advantage of errors (i.e., differences) in prices. An entrepreneur cultivates a character of alertness, looking to anticipate what consumers want. But that means that the system is ultimately driven (though perhaps passively) by consumers, not entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs are the active agents in the system, but consumers decide what firms produce and which productive activities will be rewarded and which punished.

The verger, Mr. Foreman, corrected an error in the system. There should have been a tobacconist there, in that spot. No one else recognized that, but the absence of a tobacconist was a mistake. Consumers wanted a store there (though even consumers may not have recognized this fact).

That’s what I mean about being confused about the direction of causation: one doesn’t have merit, and then receive rewards. The entrepreneur seeking profits creates something new, correcting a mistake. If the costs of correcting the mistake are less than the benefits in terms of (as I discussed earlier) the consumer surplus created, the result is profits.

There is no particular reason to expect that education or intellectual interests are an advantage in cultivating a habit of awareness of the sort that Kirzner highlights. But there are very good reasons to argue that profits, deserved or not, are something that entrepreneurs should be morally entitled to seek.

Michael Munger is a professor of economics at Duke University and a senior fellow of the American Institute for Economic Research. This article was first published at AIER.org
Michael Munger
Senior Fellow
Michael Munger is Professor of Economics at Duke University and Senior Fellow of the American Institute for Economic Research. This article was first published at AIER.org. 
Author’s Selected Articles
Related Topics